^JrrsrutciJtiTtl) OF THE THE MODERN DISTRIBUTIVE PROCESS- OF COMPETITION AND ITS LIMITS, OF THE NATURE AND AMOUNT OF PROFITS, AND OF THE DETERMINATION OF WAGES, IN THE INDUSTRIAL SOCIETY OF TO-DAY BY JOHN B.f CLARK, AUTHOR OF THE " PHILOSOPHY OK WEALTH," AND FRANKLIN I if GIDDINGS. BOSTON : PUBLISHED BY GINN & COMPANY. 1888. LONDON: TROBNER A CO. COPYRIGHT, 1888, BY JOHN B. CLARK AND FRANKLIN H. GIDDINGS. TYPOGRAPHY BY J. S. GUSHING & Co., BOSTON. PRESSWORK BY GINN & COMPANY, BOSTON. PREFACE. A SYSTEMATIC restatement of the facts and laws of the Distribution of Wealth is not attempted in these studies. Nothing is said in them, except incidentally, of interest and rent. They are studies of the process by which the income of modern society is divided among its principal claimants. There is presented to the student of to-day a more highly organized industrial system, and a more complicated process of apportioning the social income, than those that were observed by Adam Smith, David Ricardo, and John Stuart Mill. By the operations of trade the total product of industry is divided and subdivided among certain naturally constituted groups and sub-groups. The income fall- ing to each sub-group is apportioned among its component economic classes, capitalists, laborers, etc., by the bargains that they make with each other. In each of these dividing acts, artificial combinations, — the pools, trusts, labor unions, etc., of recent times, — have come to play a part so prominent that competition would seem, at the first view, to be abolished at important points. The mode of its working has been, in so changed as to demand a new scientific treatment. the aim of these studies to analyze the natural group system of iern industry; to determine where within it competition is possible, and whore combination is naturally invited ; to ascertain the extent to h this movement checks individual rivalry ; and to determine the nature and scope of that residual competition which is the controlling principle of the new regime. They thus undertake to separate that from that which is permanent in the Ricardian Theory rrihution. They analyze into its elements the - illy termed profits, and show that an essential element, the only part of the gross sum to h the tcr: mfit can be applied, has not been clearly distin- guished by the traditional analysis, and that, as a matter of course, the special laws that determine its amoun not been established. They show that the tendency of modern competition is to sweep this iv PREFACE. pure profit out of existence, while that of other forces is to cause it con- tinually to reappear. The view of social evolution which these conclu- sions afford is that of a progress toward equity between men promoted :nbinations, but guaranteed by the deeper and more general in- e of competition itself. Injustice is diminishing, and that by natural law. These studies, however, take especially into account the ethical consciousness of society, which not only sets up an ideal toward which society should tend, but, by public opinion, by legislation, and in many subtle but effective ways promotes the natural movement in that direction. The complementary character of these essays by two writers is not a premeditated result of joint authorship. The joint authorship was agreed upon, because it was discovered that, working independently, the writers had arrived at complementary conclusions. The essays were originally published in the Political Science Quarterly, and are now re- published by the kind permission of the editors of that review. TABLE OF CONTENTS. CHAPTER I. The Limits of Competition. BY J. B. CLARK. Current economic theories deducible from the assumption of unlimited compe- tition. Ricardo's system originally based on actual changes in industry; the conditions of his time transitional. The contest between weak competi- tors and strong ones, in certain industries, now decided; the strong only surviving, and these forming confederacies for the purpose of checking competition. Labor doing the same. Predatory competition vaguely con- ceived; Professor Cairnes' effort to obtain a systematic theory of it. His conception of cost of production, and his theory of non-competing groups. These groups now practically merged. Machinery the chief leveller. Sur- viving groups based on intellectual and moral differences among workmen. Entrffreneur's labor more permanently separated from other labor. Lev- elling tendencies specially active in America; these tendencies resisted by trades unions; the resistance in the end unavailing. Competition more effectively resisted by producers' unions. Pools as based on a normal principle, to be regulated, but not suppressed. A typical producing group, consisting of sub-groups or strata, each containing capitalists and laborers. True competition confined by nature within the horizontal lines that sepa- rate strata. Radical difference between this grouping and that of Professor Cairnes. Abnormal competition the cause of combinations. Control of prices their aim ; the restricting of production the means employed. Resid- ual competition still an efficient regulator of prices. Combinations 1 to natural groups; fewness of competitors a cause of union; coinj> equality among them a necessary condition. Pools impossible in n^iuul- ture. The effect of cheap transportation. Protective tariffs aids to national n«l barriers against international ones. Legal regulation of pools desirable; the complete suppression of them neither desirable nor possible. VI TABLE OF CONTENTS. CHAPTER II. The Persistence of Competition. BY F. H. GIDDINGS. The principle of competition fundamental in English Political Economy. Studies and predictions of Mr. Bagehot. The theory of Professor Cairnes. Recent revival of non-competitive methods. Suppression of competi- tion predicted. Combinations play an increasingly important part, but competition not destroyed. In some form a permanent economic process. The combination equilibrium unstable. History of combinations. Fall of prices. The nail combinations. Trunk line railroad allotments. Coal combinations. The wall paper pool. Conditions determining the area within which combinations can govern market competition. The industrial structure of society. Two kinds of non-competing groups. Any one combination usually confined within a single group. The groups unlike in composition and unequal in condition. Combination difficult in some, easy in others. When combination restrictions are beneficial. What becomes of the competitive forces. Development of new utilities. Steel substitutes for iron. Production of Bessemer steel. The higher forms of competition. Combinations cannot keep production below the full supply of society's needs. Nor prices above the level that yields aver- age returns to labor and capital. The competitive forces. Efficiency of combinations varies with industrial prosperity. Combination Policy. Essential principles of Ricardian Economics re-affirmed. CHAPTER III. Profits under Modern Conditions. BY J. B. CLARK. Danger to society from vague ideas concerning business profits. Entrepreneur's returns not scientifically analyzed. These returns the result of two unlike functions; an employer, first, a directive laborer, and secondly, a merchant. A manufacturer, a purchaser of raw materials, and of certain shares of the utilities created in the manufactory. The workmen's share paid for in wages, and the capitalist's in interest. Pure profit the difference between the total amount paid for the elements of the product, and the amount received for the product. Labor and capital involved in the mercantile part of the business; payment for them included in wages and interest. The TABLE OF CONTENTS. \\\ mere acquiring and surrendering of ownership the essence of the entre- preneur's function. The above analysis not vitiated by the uniting of sev- eral functions in one person. The elements in the cost of a product not controlled by the employer; the selling price of it not controlled by him. Pure profit determined by general and irresistible forces. This sum capable of being reduced by bad management, but not of being increased beyond a certain point by good management. Competition, a cause of high and com- paratively uniform managing ability in rival establishments. The division of the labor of management conducive to this result. Contrasts between the law of Rent and that of Profits; the area of cultivation extending; the range of managing ability narrowing. Tendency of wages of management toward uniformity. Tendency of the law of increasing returns in general business to produce a normal and permanent over-production. The pres- ence of experimenters in the business field a disturbing influence. The natural check upon too high wages of management. Pure mercantile profit the only conceivable sum from which great additions to general wages can come. This profit in reality a vanishing sum, having, in a competitive sys- tem, only a local and temporary existence. The effect of alternations from business activity to depression, and that of the opening of a continent to settlement. The effect of invention; the profit gained by this means a guar- anty for civilization. The entire gain from invention transferred, in the end, to society. The testimony of statistics to the general truth of the foregoing principles. The tendency of industrial development to connect personal rewards with services rendered to society. CHAPTER IV. The Natural Rate of Wages. BY F. H. GIDDINGS. Two sets of forces operating with reference to the rate of wages. Automatic forces of competition. Self-conscious forms of human feeling and opin- Three different views among economists. The true wages problem. Standards of just wages. Communistic and individualistic ideals. No absolute contradiction. The natural value of work. The rule of ideal distribution. The English doctrine of the natural rate of wages. Adam Smith's definition. Ricardo's theorem. John Stunrt Mill's criticism. The soul of truth in the Ricardian idea. The natural rate of wages is the rate that calls out the laborer's potential efficiency. The economical rate if also the ethical rntc. The actual rate of wages. The wages fund do, Cobden's formula. Competition of employers raises wages notwithstanding Ylll TABLE OF CONTENTS. the economy of consolidations. Analogy of rent. Improving industry multiplies employers or compels the original number to divide their gains with the laborers. The actual rate of wages tends to conform to the nat- ural or ethical rate. Exceptions to the rule. The competitive process inherently defective. Exploitation of wages. No automatic correction that meets the case. True significance of the ratio of capital to population. "Where altruism fails. Associated self-defence of labor necessary. What labor organizations and legislation can accomplish. The sums that can be added to wages. Economic analysis of the strike. Principles governing the coherence of labor organizations. Mistake of the Knights of Labor. Arbitration and legislation subject to the same principles. The rate of wages made mainly by competitive forces. Moral forces acting through organization and public opinion correct distributive errors due to defects in the competitive process. Carried farther, legislation and demands of organi- zations but retard progress. THE LIMITS OF COMPETITION. THERE is a sense in which much of the orthodox system of political economy is eternally true. Conclusions reached by valid reasoning are always as true as the hypotheses from which they are. deduced. If we admit the fact of unlimited competition, we concede in advance many doctrines which cur- rent opinion is now disposed to reject. This refuge will always be open to the latter-day defenders of the faith, as they are confronted by greater and greater discrepancies between their system and the facts of life ;4t will remain forever true that if unlimited competition existed, most of the traditional laws would be realized in the practical world. It will also be true that in those corners of the industrial field which still show an approximation to Ricardian competition there will be seen as much of correspondence between theory and fact as candid reasoners claim. If political economy will but content itself with this kind of truth, it need never be disturbed by industrial revolutions. The science need not trouble itself to progress. This hypothetical truth, or science of what would take place if society were fashioned after an ideal pattern, is not what Ricardo believed that he nad discovered. His system was posi- tive; actual life suggested it by developing tendencies for which the scientific formulas which at that time were traditional could not account. It was a new industrial world which called for a i nized system of economic doctrine. Ricardo was the first to understand the situation, to trace the new tendencies to their consummation, and to create a scientific system by insight ami .,ht. He outran history in the process, and mentally d a world more relentlessly competitive than any which has existed ; and yet it was fact and not imagination that lay at the basis of the whole system. Steam had been utili/ed, ma- chines were supplanting hand labor, workmen were migrating to new centres of production, guild regulations were giving 2 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. and competition of a type unheard of before was beginning to prevail. A struggle for existence had commenced between parties of unequal strength. In manufacturing industries the balance of power had been disturbed by steam, and the little shops of for- mer times were disappearing. The science adapted to such conditions was an economic Darwinism ; it embodied the laws of a struggle for existence between competitors of the new and predatory type and those of the peaceable type which formerly possessed the field. Though the process was savage, the out- look which it afforded was not wholly evil. The survival of crude strength was, in the long run, desirable. Machines and factories meant, to every social class, cheapened goods and more comfortable living. Efficient working establishments were de- veloping ; the social organism was perfecting itself for its con- test with crude nature. It was a fuller and speedier dominion over the earth which was to result from the concentration of human energy now termed centralization. The error unavoidable to the theorists of the time lay in basing a scientific system on the facts afforded by a state of j-evolutiorh This was attempting to derive permanent princi- ples from transient phenomena. Some of these principles must become obsolete ; and the work demanded of modern econo- mists consists in separating the transient from the permanent in the Ricardian system. How much of the doctrine holds true when the struggle between unequal competitors is over, and when a few of the very strongest have possession of the field ? Can the old-time competition be trusted to divide the fruits of industry between one overgrown shop and another, and between the owners and the workmen in each ? Can this same force control railroads, as it once controlled stage-coaches and packet- sloops ? To be more accurate, are the transactions of consoli- dated railroad lines governed by the same principles as those of single railroads and stage-coach lines when these are com- peting with each other ? Does the old regulating principle at present exist, and will general well-being continue to evolve itself under its unaided influence ? An economic system THE LIMITS OF COMPETITION'. 3 adapted to the modern era must begin by answering these questions. In most branches of manufacturing, and in other than local transportation, the contest between the strong and the weak is either settled or in process of rapid settlement. The survivors are becoming so few, so powerful, and so nearly equal that if the strife were to continue, it would bid fair to involve them all in a common ruin. What has actually developed is not such a battle of giants, ^but a system of armed neutralities and feel tions^of giants. The new era is distinctively one of consolida- ted forces; rival establishments are_forming cnmbinati n is extejuding-itself-lo-the labor and the. capital in each of them. Laborers, who_once ^competed with e^ch other, are now making their bargains collectively with their employers. ''Employers, wht> under the old regime would have worked independently, are merging their capital in cor- porations, and allowing it to be managed as by a single hand. \Ve need Ricardo's insight and foresight if we are to attajn the j economic laws that are to govern the transactions of the pi | tical world. The changes which we are witnessing are as s: ling in character as those which he witnessed, and are ( scale of greater magnitude. "There is this difference between his scientific position and ours, namely, that he saw before him an interval of contest that must of necessity, sooner or later, come to an end ; while we see approaching a of union which gives a promise of indefinite continuant studied the evolution that created a type of industrial CM lishment ; we have to study the functions of this survi History will aid us by furnishing a point of depart and by indicating the direction of social development, but not by giving facts from which any possible induction can give the principles which we seek. The light derivable from past facts t derivable from present tendencies is posit •The materials for study lie in the present and the immediate I future ; and, to be scientific, we must be somewhat prophet ie. f JVedatory competition between unequal parties was the basis^ of t irdian system. This process was vaguely conceived 4 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. and never fully analyzed ; what was prominent in the thought of men in connection with it was the^ single clement of struggle. Mere_effort to survive, the Darwinian feature of the process, was all that, in some uses, the term competition was made to designate. *Yet the competitive action of an organized society is systematic ; each part of it is limited to a specific field, and tends, within these limits, to self-annihilation. ^ An effort to attain a conception of competition that should remove some of the confusion was made by Professor Cairnes. His system of " non-competing groups " is a feature of his value theory, which is a noteworthy contribution to economic thought. Mr. Mill had followed Ricardo in teaching that the natural price of commodities is governed by the cost of producing them. Professor Cairnes accepts this statement, but attaches to it a meaning altogether new. He says, in effect : Commodities do indeed exchange according to their cost of produc- tion ; but cost is something quite different from what currently passes by that name. That is merely the outlay incurred by the capitalist- employer, for raw materials, labor, etc. The real cost is the personal sacrifice made by the producing parties, workmen as well as employers. It is not a mercantile but a psychological phenomenon, a reaction upon the men themselves occasioned by the effort of the laborer and the abstinence of the capitalist. These personal sacrifices gauge the market value of commodities within the fields in which, in the terms of the theory, competition is free. The adjustment takes place through the spontaneous movement of capital and labor from employments that yield small returns to those that give larger ones. Capital migrates freely from place to place and fmm occupation to occupation. If one indus- try is abnormally profitablJiJLapital seeks it, increases and cheapens its product, and reduces its profits tq the prevailing level. Profits tend to a general uniformity. Wages are said to tend to equality only within limits. The transfer of labor from one employment to another is checked by barriers. What we find, in effect [continues Professor Cairnes], is not a whole population competing indiscriminately for all occupations, but a series of industrial layers, superimposed on one another, within each of which the various candidates for employment possess a real and effective power of THE LIMITS OF COMPETITION-. 5 selection, while those occupying the several strata are, for all purposes of effective competition, practically isolated from each other. We may perhaps venture to arrange them in some such order as this : first, at the bottom of the scale there would be the large group of unskilled or nearly unskilled laborers, comprising agricultural laborers, laborers engaged in ellaneous occupations in towns, or acting in attendance on skilled labor. Secondly, there would be the artisan group, comprising skilled laborers of the secondary order, — carpenters, joiners, smiths, masons, shoemakers, tailors, hatters, etc., etc., — with whom might be included the very large class of small retail dealers, whose means and position place them within the reach of the same industrial opportunities as the class of artisans. The third layer would contain producers and dealers of a higher order, whose work would demand qualifications only obtainable by persons of substantial means and fair educational opportunities ; for example, civil and mechanical engineers, chemists, opticians, watch- makers, and others of the same industrial grade, in which might also find a place the superior class of retail tradesmen ; while above these there would be a fourth, comprising persons still more favorably circumstanced, whose ampler means would give them a still wider choice. This last group would contain members of the learned professions, as well as per- sons engaged in the various careers of science and art, and in the higher branches of mercantile business. It is essential to the theory that not only workmen but their children should be confined to a producing group. The equal- izing process may take place even though men do not actually abandon one occupation and enter another ; for there exists, in the generation of young men not yet committed to any occupa- tion, a disposable fund of labor, which will gravitate naturally to the occupations that pay the largi * s. It is not ne^ sary that blacksmiths should ever bcAfa* shoemakers, or vice v7, but only that the children of 1 -ses of artisans should 1 '> enter the trade that is best rewarded. lessor Cairnes does not claim that his classification is Lfttive, nor that the demarcation is absolute : No doubt the various ranks and classes fade into each other by imper- •i'hlc gradations, and individuals from all classes are constantly pass- up or dropping down ; but while this is so, it is nevertheless true that the average workman, from \\ ' nk he be taken, finds his •;on limited for practical purposes to a certain range of 6 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. occupations, so that, however high the rates of remuneration in those which lie beyond may rise, he is excluded from sharing them. Wo are thus Compelled to recognize the existence of non-competing industrial groups as a feature of our_socjar economy. It will be seen that the competition which is here under dis- cussion is of an extraordinary kind ; and the fact that the gen- eral term is applied to it without explanation is a proof of the vagueness of the conceptions of competition with which acute writers have contented themselves. Actual competition con^ sists invariably in an effort_to_undersell a rival producer. A carpenter competes with a carpenter because he creates a simi- lar utility, and offers it in the market. In the theory of Pro- fessor Cairnes the carpenter is the competitor of the blacksmith, because his children may enter the blacksmith's calling^ In_ the actual practice of his own trade, the one artisan in nowise affects the other. It_is potential competition_rather than actual that_is here under discussion; and even this depends for its effectiveness on the action of the rising generation. (Tost, in the sense of_ personal ^acrifice, ^gpyer_ning_prices within the fields in which potential competition_exists, is the summary of this noteworthy theory. The criticism to be made upon it is that the application of its more fundamental princi- ple, that which connects the prices of commodities with the sacrifices involved in producing them, is, in modern industry, far wider than the author of the theory supposed, and wider than it was, in fact, in European countries at the time when he published his work. The limitations which he imposed on the action of this principle are no longer necessary, and the four- fold grouping of laborers according to their personal qualities no longer corresponds with anything in actual life. Modern methods of production have obliterated Professor Cairnes' dividing lines. Potential competition^xtends to every part_ojjthejndustrial Afield in which men work in organized com- panies. -Throwing out of account the professions, a few trades of the highest sort, and the class of labor which is performed by employers themselves and their salaried assistants, it is practically true that labor is in a universal ebb and flow; it THE LIMITS OF COMPETITION. 7 passes freely to occupations which are, for the time being, highly paid, and reduces their rewards to the general level. •/ This objection to the proposed grouping is not theoretical. The question is one of fact ; it is the development of actual industry that has invalidated the theory which, ten years ago, ( expressed an important truth concerning economic relations in / 1 ;: inland. Moreover, the author of the theory anticipated one change which would somewhat lessen its applicability to future conditions. He recorded his belief that education would prove a leveller, and that it would merge to some extent the strata of '.ust rial a The children of hod-carriers might become machinists, accountants, or lawyers when they could acquire the needed education, ^tle admitted also that new countries afford conditions in which the lines of demarcation are faint. is not in a position to appreciate the chief levelling agency, namely, the machine method of production as nojy extended and perfected. Education makes the laborer capable of things relatively difficult, and machines render the processes which he needs to master relatively easy. The so-called un- skilled workmen stand on a higher personal level than those of former times ; and the new methods of manufacturing are reducing class after class to that level. Mechanical labor is resolvii into processes so simple that any one may learn them. An old-time shoemaker could not become a watchmaker, and even his children would have found difficulties in their way had they attempted to master the higher trade ; but a laster in a Lynn shoe factory can, if he will, learn one of the minute fles that are involved in the making of a Waltham watch. > children may do so without difficulty; and this is all that is necessary for maintaining the normal balance between the trad i f *, sun iving^differences between workmen are 'dily strength still counts for something, and ength, for more; but the consideration which chiefly iK mines tin value of a workman to the employer who entrusts to him costly Is and a del i the question of fidelity. Character is not monopoli/ed by any social 8 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. is of universal growth, and tends, by the prominent part which it plays in modern industry, to reduce to their lowest terms the class differences of the former era. The rewards of professional life are gauged primarily by character and native endowment, and are, to this extent, open to the children of workmen. New barriers, however, arise here^ in the ampler education which, as^ time advances, is demanded of persons in these pursuits ; and these barriers give to a part of the fourth and highest class in the scheme that we are criticising a permanent basis of existence. ' .Another variety of labor retains a pre-eminence based on native adapta- tions and special opportunities. It is the work of the employer himself. It is an organizing and directing function, and in large industries is performed only in part by the owners. A portion of this work is committed to hired assistants. Strictly speaking, the entrepreneur, or employer, of a great establishment is not one man, but many, who work in a collective capacity, and who receive a reward that, taken in the aggregate, con- stitutes the "wages of superintendence." To some members of this administrative body the returns come in the form of salaries, while to others they come partly in the form of divi- dends ; but if we regard their work in its entirety, and consider their wages in a single sum, we must class it with entrepreneur s profits rather than with ordinary wages. It is a different part of the product from the sum distributed among day-laborers ; and this fact separates the administrative group from the class considered in our present inquiry. Positions of the higher sort are usually gained either through the possession of capital, or through relations to persons who possess it. ^Though clerkships of the lower grade demand no attainments which the children of workmen cannot gain, and though promotion to the higher grades is still open, the tendency of the time is to make the transition from the ranks of labor to those of administration more and more difrJcultXThe true laboring class is merging its subdivisions, while it is separating more sharply from the class whose interests, in test questions, place them on the side of capital. THE LIMITS OF COMPETITION'. 9 ~ If we consider individuals of the higher group, we shall find that the grounds for classifying them separately from wage- workers are not always distinct: It may be doubtful whether a particular man should be rated as a workman, or as a subor- dinate member of the employer's staff. In the case of respon- sible managers this uncertainty disappears. The manager of a great manufactory does what is clearly identified as entrepreneur s work, and receives a reward which, in the minds of those who pay it, stands in a recognized ratio to the product which is secured by his efficiency. Such a man is identified with em- ployers in interest, acts with them when labor conflicts arise, and carries with him the staff of assistants who help to execute his plans and, in some degree, share his fortunes. 'Here lies -M ntial distinction between salaried labor and the true \v a^c-labor to which our inquiry is now confined.^ * America affords the conditions most favorable to the levelling process which is reducing the workman proper to a single social stratum/ To this extent our democracy has an economic basis. education anH n^fjve versatility elevate the lower sub- strata, while machine processes depress the higher. High general wages assist, by placing within the reach of the children of the state that modicum of training which opens many callings to their selection. The barriers that separated irners into broad non-competing strata are, to all intents and purj things of th< Art may create barriers where nature has destroyed frh^rn The concerted action of men may set in motion aristocratizing influences, where a natural evolution would lead to democracy. Trades unions may obstruct the transfer of labor from one OCCU- i to an a partial monopoly of favored employments. Restrictions on apprenticeships like those which led among the mediaeval guilds might, if carried: :e around each of the minute trades which ctory system has developed, and substitute for the gc strata of former times an ajlificial grouping- far morc undcmo- cratic in i* working. Labor organization has i: taken this course., {o an extent that produces appreciable i 10 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. onj-clative wages. The boy who has both time and ability to learn a trade is not always permitted to do so ; and hence arises the need of trade schools, especially in self-governing countries. It is an important question whether the principle of equality and consequent fraternity is to prevail over the artificial tendency to exclusiveness and antagonism. In the long run and in the general field it must prevail^; the forces in its favor are too pow- erful to be resisted. -The education which increases men's working ability, the change of method which makes less and less demands on that ability, supplemented by the public senti- ment that revolts at the policy of denying, to men the oppor- tunity to do what they can for themselves and for society, will keep within bounds the effort to monopolize skill by reviving guild regulations. ' Trades unions may, for some time, interpose obstacles to the free transfer of labor to the points of greatest demand, which is the potential competition of Professor Cairnes' theory ; but^ in the long run, causes beyond arbitrary control i^^ freex Itjs not workmen but employers who have erected the chief artificialjbarriers against competition. A startling recent devel- opment is the system of combinations by which producers of particular articles have attempted arbitrarily to control^ the supply and the market value of their respective products. This apparently wholesale abrogation of economic law was unthought of by early economists ; and although in Professor Cairnes' time the pooling process had begun, even he regarded capital as in a universal ebb and flow, ready to move spontaneously to the point where it could gain the largest returns. Toward the close of what we have termed the century of transition, pro- ducers' combinations appeared on a large scale ; and very lately they have stolen a forced march upon economists. While we slept, as it were, and dreamed of the regulation of values""by the automatic flow of capital to the points of highest profit, the principle apparently ceased to operate within very extensive fields. It would be easy to name a hundred staple articles, like glass, wall-paper, cut nails, screws, files, spool silk, anthra- cite coal, steel rails, etc., of which the supply and the market THE LIMITS OF COMPETITION'. \ \ value are fixed by agreement by strong associations of producers. The scientific significance of this transition is a question for immediate study. Have we come unconsciously under a regime of arbitrary values ? Igjhe old regulating princ mpetition, ;ated_? Is it subject to disturbances so vast and uncertain as to baffle scientific calculation ? The practical inquiry must be guided here as elsewhere by a study of principles. Combinations have their roots in the nature of social industry__and are normal in their origin, their development, and their practical working. Thevare neither to bedeprecated by scientists nor suppressed by legislators. They are the^s^jroT^h~evoIutiqn, and are the happy outcome of a competition so abnormal that the continuance of it would have >readruin. A successful attempt to suppress them \v would involve the reversion of industrial systems to a cast-off type, the renewal of abuses from which society has escaped by a step in development. Combinations are to be accepted, studied, and, probably, regulated ; they qughtjiot ta be suppressed if such j^ction_were practicable. This action is fortunately not practicable except in the early stages of their growth, while their form is still crude, and while the initial diffi- culties of the system are great. The repressive policy may for a time, succeed ; but it must be at the cost of social ;radation and economic loss. Modern production is not an individualistic process ; it is the act of society as a whole, and each separate man in the ranks his fuii -Towly limited. Parts of the productive operation are assigned to sub-organizations, and these are sub- jected to a discipline which limits « i. h mpmhir tn an infinjjggi imal part of general industry. He may be one of a group that collectively cuts trees, or of another that saws logs, or of another that fashions lumber into furniture. The chair that a primitive r would have hewn out with an axe is the product of one of the numerous sub-organisms of society. The relations of sub-organisms to each other, though intricate, are capable of clear analysis. \Ye « ne for study, and, to ; confusion, consider no relations that are not essential to 12 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. our present purpose. Crudely represented, the furniture-making group arranges itself as follows : Finishing Cabinet making Transporting Lumber dealing Wood cutting Each stratum shows a subdivision into capitalists and work- men ; and in each case there range themselves on the side of the capitalists a few men of managing ability, who constitute with their employer a sort of collective entrepreneur, and whose rewards, in the form of salaries, have more in common with profits than they have with wages. True competition is limited by nature to the strata here in- dicated ; cutters compete only with cutters, lumber dealers with lumber dealers, etc. 'The distinction between this grouping and that of Professor Cairnes consists, not in the fact that the classification here proposed follows the lines of occupation, Jbut_ in_the_fact that it is based on real and not on potential compe- tition. ^Whether a workman can or cannot transfer himself from one sub-group to another is a question which we do not raise. ) We_inc[uire simply with whom he competes while re- n_lm_^ tcL discharge his special function. In this lies the practical fruit to be gained by a study of the grouping. As bearing on the direct adjustment of relative wages, the question to be considered is : Whether wood-cutters are potential competitors of furniture makers, etc. ; whether they or their children have such a choice of occupa- tions open to them that the rewards of all tend toward a general uniformity ? As bearing on the question which we are now con- sidering, the point to be studied is : J|Vhat_gi^^^of men_are brought into competition with each other by the nature of their industrial functions, and what consequences result from this grouping? KU is to be noted, moreover, that_m the sale of com- modities, Jinished or unfinished, the competition is not between THE LIMITS OF COMPETITION \ 3 workmen, nor between^mployers, scparately_con§idfiied, but between industrial establi- in their entirety. One furniture manufactory as a whole competes with another. Each is an organism in itself; and although the employer in each case becomes the owner of the product, and places it in his own name upon the market, yet his relations with his men are such as to make them partners in the sacrifice which creates the product, and in the rewards derived from it. It is the of both workmen^ jind j5mployersf and_the_relations between the that determine_the__competing ability^ of an industrial estab- Competitionjn the sale of commodities is limitedto Mishmcnts of the same sub-class ; it is confined by nature in horizontal lines like those which, in the case of one representative group, we have indicated in the foregoing am. ^Xhe&e subgroups, are now solidifying. Within many of the pairs of parallel lines competition has exterminated the weak iucers, and becoming fiercer as the survivors become fewer and stronger, isjcompelling themf in the end, to unite or perish. " Let us have peace " has become the watchword in this part of the field ; and the truce which has ensued has taken the fqnnjrf tern of producers' combinations. nions^ aim to fix prices and, as a means thereto, to rest r i ct production. The_onej>rocess limits actual competition, and the other potential. To decide upon a price list, and to abide by it, is to allay the rivalry between similar producers ; to restrict production is to disturb the relations between dis- similar producers. An^arbitrary restrict inn upon the amount of a commodity which can be place < the industry, and thus obstructs the transfer ;tal fr«»m group to group — which is the tial competition of Professor ( theory. Could each group solidify into a corporation that could control its members within and s rivalry without, the whole industrial field would definitely non-competitive. The old regulator of values won stTand the ;• intervention would ac- quire great force. The study of the coming interval is that of 14 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. the principles which make a general appeal of this kind un- necessary. It is the study of competition in residual forms. The process is taking on an advanced type, less simple than that of earlier times, and more legitimate than that which has / lately developed. R^s^dua^competition of the actual kind sub- sists between_rjroductive establishments of comparatively equal strength in co.mbinaiion with each other; and residual competi- tion of the potential kind is maintained between the entire combination and the remainder of society. The members of the pool are still rivals ; and capital and labor may still transfer themselves to and from the industry which they try to control. Monopoly prices have not been long maintained by any of these organizations ; and this fact is due, not to chance, but to com- plex and interesting economic laws. Leaving the discussion of these principles to one whose analysis derives weight from practical observation, I close this paper with a brief reference to the rmTrjjj-inngjv^ tV>p transition from thj^era of predatory cormoetitiQa t«~> that o£-u»ion. If each industry were represented by a diagram like the one by which we have rudely shown the relation of sub-classes in the furniture-making group, it would be found that the horizon- tal lines which bound the fields of competition bound also those of combination. ""The combining groups are the natural compet- ing groups of industrial society. The limitation of these fields is important. The fewer are the competitors, the fiercer is the strife^n4jthe^_greater is the need jrf_ union. Thejgwer are the competitors, the easier is the pooling^^rocgss. The effect of the union is to turn the belligerent energies of society in a new direction. Un^rtheldstem it destroyed each other ; under the new system jt_Js producers of dissimilar articles whose intfjrggFg^nmpjjitO nvrrt ronfh'ct To limit the supply and raise the price of a commodity is to make members of other producing groups give for it an increased proportion of their own products ; and if this attempt is met by a similar proceeding on their part, there results an industrial war, the battles of which are fought across the horizontal lines, instead of between them. If unions were general, the lumber- THE LIMITS OF COMPETITION'. 15 men of the foregoing diagram would cease to attack each other, and collectively do battle with the transporters and furniture makers. Treaties of alliance on the old battle-ground, hostility at the point of former amity. — such are the results of the tran- sitionjp the new systcmf The field of economic war and the nature of the belligerent process are both changed. ie product of a social evolution, and can no permanent existence until the Darwinian contest be- tween the weak and the strong has completed its work. The ving competitors must be_Jew, strong, and neariy_equal. Marked inequalities of strength among the members of the .group defer the formation of the union, or break it when it is formed prematurely. Rivals do not combine so long as one is conscious of the power to exterminate the other. 'Moreover, strength for such a contest consists not merely in the size of a producing establishment, although that is an element to be con- sidered ; it consists primarily in advantages for economical pjo- duction. Location is important, but the paramount influence is the mastery of cheap methods."' Natural selection ; industries in the most tavorable localities, and brings them to some equality in method ; and until this is done there is no chance for an economic truce. In agriculture the number of competitors bars the way for the formation of unions? It is to be noted that the prices of food products arc ive to c; \\ supply ; and if a combination could restrict the crops uniformly and very moder ately, it could force the members of other industrial departments to pay double or quadruple for the means of living. .st such a calamity the nature of the agricultural industry jntcrposes its bar. Anthracite coal is somewhat like a food product in its importance, and in the variations which the changes in the supply. Coal-min- is strong; inducements and exceptional facilities for the pooling process, and it is here that the effects of union are. eapeHnlly frnrmfnl jo sorirty 'I 1 hus far done fiasnot been greater than it has been is due to residual com- petit: -h it has worked under unusual disadvantages. 1 6 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. The value of this regulating agent under favorable circum- Portability in the commodity produced is essential to the formation of a combination on a national scale.^jrhe large estab- lishment must be able to reach with its product the entire ter- ritory, and that without incurring a cost for transportation which would prevent it from underselling the small local producers." Baskets are made with great economy in a large shop ; but their bulk subjects them to a cost for transportation that enables the local manufacturers, though working with less economy, to hold their respective fields, and defeats the formation of a union in this industry. In the silk manufacture the freight costs practi- cally nothing, and the mill which produces cheaply has at its command all parts of the national territory to which its agents choose to travel. The silk industry offers, in this respect, a favorable field for combination. ^Moreover, cheapness of trans- portatiorTcTepelids not only on the nature of a product, but also on the development of an efficient railroad system^ The low rates for freight now prevailing in this country have done much to create combinations among manufacturers ; if pools among the railroads themselves were to restore the former cost of transportation, they would undo this work. The economic war between transporters and other groups of industrial society promises to result so favorably to the other groups as to facili- tate combinations among them. In but few instances has the principle of union among pro- ducers shown a capacity to cross national lines ; and in so far as a protective tariff debars the foreigner from being an efficient competitor within the limits of a country, it hastens the forma- _tion of pools within those limits. In any case foreign com- petition acts as a check upon the raising of prices after a combination has been formed. The industrial world would seem to be dividing into two por- tions, in one of which, embracing the most important of all forms of production, namely, tjTat_gf_agriculture1Jhe_principle ofjndiyidual comrjetition continues, and produces-results so beneficial to society:. as to_justify the enthusiasm of the early THE LIMITS OF COMPETITION'. ij economists for competition as a regulator of values and a divider of the fruits of industry. In the other economic divis- ion, embracing transportation and a majority of manufactures, theprinciple of combination is asserting itself, and introducing a regime in which prices are regulated by competition in latent forms. Whether these surviving types of competi- tion are so nearly adequate to the regulating work which must be done that no state action is called for, is a debatable question. Whether state action should take the form of a legal suppres- sion of combinations is a question which a brief trial of such a policy would place beyond the debatable line. To regulate combinations is possible and, in some directions, desirable ; to permanently suppress them is impossible^; to temporarily re- prcss_thcm is either to force them into illegal forms, or to restore the internecine war from which a natural evolution has delivered us., To accept the results of this evolution and to meetjhejiemands of the new era is the part of wisdom. JOHN B. CLARK. THE PERSISTENCE OF COMPETITION. THE late Walter Bagehot probably knew the " market " better than any other thinker who has grappled with theoretical questions of political economy. This fact lends weight to his views of the present, past, and future of compe- tition, as presented in those luminous essays on The Postulates of Englisli Political Economy, written just before his death. John Stuart Mill had said that " only through the principle of competition has political economy any pretension fo thf> rb^rFT- ter of a science/' 1 — a dictum that compressed into a sentence the economic system of Ricardo, James Mill, Senior, and McCulloch. John Stuart Mill himself distinctly recognized the hypothetical character of this system, and in the chapter on " Competition and Custom " he undertook to show that it was only the wholesale trade and the great articles _of__£om- merce that were really under the dominion .ofL competition. A\. the same time he asserted that the influence of competition was "making itself felt more and more. through the principal branches of retail trade in the large towns," and that " the rapidity and cheapness of transport, by making consumers less dependent on the dealers in their immediate neighborhood," were " tending to assimilate more and more the whole country to a large town.'*/ Mr. Bagehot, bringing to his investigations a rare mastery of deductive reasoning, a breadth of view gained by many excursions into the domains of history and physical science, and the worldly sagacity of a practical business man of Lombard Street, became convinced *nat the fundamental postu- lates of English political economy, besides being only hypo- thetically true for a great portion of modern European society, ^vvcre not true at all for uncivilized and semi-civilized societies, nor for European societies in their primitive eras. His demon- 1 Principles of Political Economy, chapter on Competition and Custom, second paragraph. THE PERSISTENCE OF COMPETITION. 19 stration that in the undeveloped society there is no free trans- ferability of labor was based largely on the researches of such investigators as Sir Henry Sumner Maine ; but his demonstra- tion that capital was not jojransferable until very recent times, and in modern times is so transferable only in the great com- :.il nations like England, is peculiarly his own. It consists •\ving that the freejransferability of capital, and therefore the perfect com pet it inaction of capital, depends QJ namely : the existence of a vast loan fund, tlu :ice of a vast speculative fund, and the free movement of young n\ciTTnto3hose channels of business that promise the Formerly neither of these conditions existed. Until recently they existed only in financial centres like London, but to-day they exist so generally that their influence begins to be universally felt. In this fact Mr. Bagehot discerned the true cause of the rarjid_extension of competitive economics beyond the limits uf wholesale trade. The laws of the "great com- men e being irresistibly forced upon the minor com- merce. Accordingly he concluded : " As * men of the world ' are the same everywhere, so the great commerce is the same every- where. Local peculiarities and ancient modifying circumstances fall away in both cases ; and it is of this one and uniform com- merce which grows daily, and which will grow, according to every probability, more and more, that English political econ- omy , to be the explanation."2 In a word, it was Mr /< nal conclusion that the mobility of labor and_carjital_ • become practically ; and the economic science principle of janm petition." though not true at all of_the_ rid of the p become icly true_oTthe economic world of the fu: flTean while I'r J. E. Cairnes, in his attempt to adapt the deductive political economy more perfectly to the present facts of economic society, had discovered limitations of compe- tition not imposed by "local peculiarities nr anripnf mnfjifyjnjy inherent in the nature of men, and thcrg- •u'liei, edited by R. II. Hutton, pp. 45-47. 1 Economic Studies, p. 20. 20 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. fore permanent. "Here, then, in the constitution of the " non- competing groups " was an obstacle to the fulfilment of Mr. Bagehot's predictions that could by no possibility disappear.* This limitation was not regarded, however, as of the greatest importance. It would have the effect of creating a sort of stratification of prices, but within each stratum the prices of specific services and things would be determined more and more perfectly by competition. Professor Cairnes himself dis- tinctly admitted the importance of the loan and speculative funds as a competitive force. It is plain, too [he said], that the capital thus disposable is sufficient for the purpose we have here in view, namely, to render competition effective among the various industries ; since we find a portion of it con- stantly moving abroad for foreign investment — a destination it would scarcely receive while there was a prospect of reaping exceptionally high returns from investment within the country. We have, therefore, in the existence of this fund all that is required for a practically effective corn- petition, so far as one instrument of production is concerned, and this without necessitating any serious encroachment on the capital actually engaged in productive operations.1 Little more than a decade has passed, and we;witness a state of things that, to superficial observation at least, seems totally to contradict these final conclusions at which Ricardian political economy had arrived. ^Just when the disappearance of the last vestiges of a volitional restriction of competition was looked for, and the universal application of the " rule of the market " was confidently expected, we see a wide-spread revival of eco- nomic methods and agencies over which The Wealth of Nations was read as a funeral service. And most remarkable of all, it is^ not only labor, to the absolutely free competition of which natural and permanent limitations were admitted, but capital — that very agent which Mr. Bagehot said " runs as surely and instantly where it is most wanted and where there is most to be made of it, as water runs to find its level," 2 that seems to have voluntarily massed itself into a solidarity, hedged itself about 1 Leading Principles, Harper's ed., pp. 63, 64. 2 Lombard Street, p. 13. THE PERSISTENCE OF COMPETITION-. 2 1 with new and most ingenious restrictions, and bound itself by heavy penalties not to run to any new level or deviate from —wonted channels. rl nis increasing prominence ot pools and combinations has given a new direction to theoretical thought. A^ majorityjpf the working economists who have kept up with the progress of events no Iqngerjook to seejhe_supremacy of an unhind^Fcd^ competition. By not a few of the ablest investi- gators the gradual^suppression of the competition now existing is predicted^ Instead of moving toward freer competition, they affirm, we are moving away from it,1 and reasons are offered to show that in the very nature of business facts no other result possible. Not only of such vast organizations of capital as the railroad system is this tendency supposed to be true, but of almost all industries having a large permanent investment.2 New agencies for adjusting prices it is expected will be neces- sary. Between a solid body of non-competing employers on one side, jmd a solid body of non-competing workingmcn on the other, will have to stand committees of conciliation and boards of arbitration.3 The standard of tib&justum prttium% the "rea- sonable price " of the middle ages, "will be again set up and enforced by an appeal, through compulsory publicity, to public opinion.4 That combinations are to play an increasingly important part in economic affairs, is altogether probable. "l3ut that competi- tion is to be to a corresponding extent destroyed, and that arbitration and publicity are to perform any other function than that of equalizing temporary inequalities of competition, as commercial credit equalizes temporary inequalities of economic :e, or as insurance equalizes temporary inequalities of s are conclusions that should not be too hastily accepted. \Vc should be on our guard against two assumptions. We must not assume that because competition is not . observable in the form seen on the produce exchange, it^ is not discoverable jn r I JI.vM. v, Railroad Tranap 65. * H.i I mopolie* and 1 ,;hts, Quarterly Journal of EC* j, October, 1886. .he Philosophy of Wealth, p. 66. • Report of the Connecticut Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1885, pp. 16, 106. 22 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. any form. We must not assume that when market competition is imperfect it may be ignored, as if it were quite non-existent. These assumptions would be as unwarrantable as the assump- tion of the a priori economists has been in regarding the laws of the wholesale market as so nearly true of economic society everywhere and always that conflicting facts might be dis- missed as irrelevant. "That competition in some form is a per- manent economic process, is an implication of the conservation of energy. Given an aggregate of units of unequal energy, their unequal activity is an inevitable consequence. With the complexity of social environment that every quarter of the earth presents, and the limitless variations of heredity, a society com- posed of individuals of equal energy is an impossibility, there- fore, when market competition seems to have been suppressed, we should inquire what has become of the forces by which it was generated. We should inquire, further, to what degree market competition actually is suppressed or converted into other forms, and within what limits combinations can hold together and act effectively/ The combination equilibrium may be, at best, an unstable one. The economic affairs of every member are in a constant' ebb and flow. The relative advantages of members as possible competitors cannot remain long unaltered. And however nearly equal they may be at any moment in economic strength, they will be unequal morally. Not every member of a combination goes into it expecting to break the agreement, but hoping that all other members will keep it ; l but this is a true description of the conduct of some. Different producers are always unequal in respect of that larger fidelity that imparts a unique value to a commodity through care in selecting the best materials and the most careful and trustworthy workmen. ^They are unequal also in those faculties by which production is adapted to changing conditions^ The discerning and alert secure the advantages that accrue from the first production of superior substitutes for articles in common use, or the first adoption of more economical methods. Dis- turbances of equilibrium^ by_anyj)f these means may requicken 1 J. Schcenhof, The Industrial Situation, p. 74. PERSISTENCE OF COMPETITION'. 23 competition \vijliin_the combination. ^Competition may >** forged upon the combination jromjYithoiit _by the accumulation of outside capita^ ^ekinjg_emplQ^iiieiit. The latter is a force that nothing can overcome, though it may be to some extent diverted. It is the organic process of growth, multiplying cells in the vital organism, multiplying individuals in society, multi- tiplying capital in financial centres, — all crowding perpetually upon the existing means of subsistence and profitable occupa- tion, — that insures the permanence of competition throughput the whole range of organic phenomena. The history of combinations to the present time fully verifies these propositions. Combinations hav£_nflt_£rcvented the com- petitive investment of new capital, or sustained prices, or main- tained an effective discipline among their own members The general decline of prices has gone on with little interruption since 1870 ; that is, during the period within which combinations have had their phenomenal growth. Late calculations 1 give the money cost of the average daily supply of food, dry goods, boots, and fuel, for one adult, as 43.53 cents in 1870, and 30 cents in 1885. The charge for moving a ton of freight per mile over one of the trunk line pool roads is given by the same sta- tistician as 1.853 cents in 1870, and .68 cents in 1885.2 The industrial depression of 1883-84, which carried nearly all prices to a much lower level than they had reached in the previous depression of 1878-79, did not spare the goods "controlled" by combinations. As compared with the lowest prices at which; they were quoted previous to 1882, cut nails were 12 per cent in 1884, and steel rails 39 per cent lower.8 The nail infill stry affpjds a good illustration of the inability uf combina- tO withstand the COnqpetitfc* arrinn nf npw rapitnl In 1883 the Western nail association made >ts to t production by susj work. Notwithstanding this, the number of mills was im from 68, having an annual capacity of 8,500,000 kegs, to 79, with an 1 Those of Mr. Edward Atkinson in Br r 18, 1886. 1 The Relative Strength and Weakness of Nations, Th* Century, January, 1887. 1 & 10, 1885. 24 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. annual capacity of 12,500,000 kegs, and half of the increase was in the western district.1 In 1884 a new effort was made to restrict competition; but almost before it took shape the manufacture of nails from steel began, and within a year the steel nail mills that sprang up in the Wheeling district, not to mention others, had a capacity of 2,600,000 kegs per annum.2 Combinations that might be expected to be strong and efficient, because of their enjoyment of franchises and natural monop- olies, are all the while breaking because of internal disagree- ments.*^ No longer ago than the autumn of 1885 trunk line railroad business was completely disorganized because the roads could not agree on their respective allotments. *The anthracite coal combination, formed in 1873, succeeded in controlling the output for three years. Prices were gradually forced to a height that the market would not bear, and stocks accumulated, in spite of the restriction of production, until the combination broke, in August, 1876, and 500,000 tons of coal were sold at auction.*— Another attempt, made in 1878, was broken by rate- cutting by the Lehigh Valley company and the contention of the Reading company for a larger allotment. A third combina- tion lasted from 1879 to 1884, when its efficiency was destroyed by the commercial depression and the increasing resort to bituminous coal.3 A fourth arrangement, made in 1885, has been imperfectly successful. Of all the industrial combinations that have been described in alarming terms in the popular reviews and anti-monopoly organs, probably not one-tenth have continuously and effectively limited competition.^ One of the most perfectly organized and most talked about of these has been the wall-paper combination, and its fortunes have been peculiarly instructive. It was formed in 1880, and made a great deal of money. One party was paid $20,000 a year to cease production. A scale of prices was established, and every member was assigned his proportion of the total production. The penalty for underselling was a forfeit of $1000, one-half to go to the informer. Monthly meetings were held, at which every manufacturer presented a detailed statement of his sales, 1 Bradstrcet's, May 10, 1884. 2 Ibid., July 18, 1885. 8 Ibid.t January 17, 1885. THE PERSISTENCE OF COMPETITION. 25 specifying the quality and price of every roll sold, and naming the purchaser. Then the executive committee equalized the proceeds, taking from those that had oversold, and distributing among those that had not sold up to their quota. Yet, not- withstanding these elaborate precautions, competition was not prevented, either within the combination or from without. One member has chosen to pay $10,000 a year in forfeits rather than desist from underselling. H3y paying factories for keeping idle, thc^rombination has tempted so much new capital into the^ business that it is now impossible to controF product ion " The conditions determining the area within which combina- tions can govern market competition, divert it into new chan- nels, and convert it into new forms, are to be found in certain natural demarcations in the industrial structure of sock This structure, resting on the basis of crude materials, which it transforms, adapts, and consumes, is constituted by the segre- gation of men into functional groups, corresponding to the sub- divisions of industrial operations and the broader differences of °- d CO „ ™xs O . . . a u ii HVa d? Z ; 2 ii 1IVN :''.., .'J < y n XOV-L CI5 z o U (t n 3UIM cr.":> b. - 0 •I Aa3-u.no C.~'.'> I •saaonaoad Moid CO UJ ttJ CO 5 I g _J _ CC CC Q; UJ O uj co s ^ B OQ UJ SPONSIBLE BRAIN WOR TOMATIC BRAIN WOR SPONSIBLE MANUAL LA < w a' -< a ta N 5 2 |i w § * < a z °s £ 8 a* i fe UJ D UJ D I UI CC t£ i < 1- co u. O — C 73 2 lei T * o -5 V c fcJl* §•£ 'o « S ^ S W O ^ H) ^ C ."« ^ *s H •- o ^^ o -C S sion of unusual severity or duration forces one or another party to unload his stocks at any prices that he can get, regardless of combination agreements, and consummates the extinction of 1 BraJjtreet'j, December 25, 1886. 32 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. those producers whose disadvantageous situation or antiquated methods make their cost of production relatively high. On the other hand, any attempt of the combination to become an aggressive agency for the positive enrichment of its members is subject to the limitation, that the conditions that might enable a combination to force prices to an unnatural levePare the very ones that insure the most disastrous reaction upon such a policy. Mother things being equal, new capital will hesi- tate longest about entering; into competition with established producers in those industries in which each producer must have a plant that is costly in proportion to the value of the total product of all producers, t^ut the combination that would reap advantage from this hesitancy must face the fact that it is precisely this expensiveness of plant that entails heavy fixed charges, — which must be met at whatever sacrifice of profits, — and impels competition to a ruinous extreme if more capital is tempted into the business than the normal social need re- quires. A short-sighted and grasping policy by railroad com- panies and industrial combinations that might, by a liberal course, have kept entire markets to themselves, has resulted in the building of scores of railroads and hundreds of mills for which no real need existed, and the struggles of these for sub- sistence has kept rates and prices below the dividend-paying level for years together. Hence, as combinations learn their unalterable limitations in "the nature of things/' they must adjust prices and production, by a conscious policy, to the normal basis that otherwise will be reached in a more wasteful way. y/They must permit the full satisfaction of normal demands and allow prices to gravitate^to an equality with cost of production"^ If there is really room for new plant, and new capital seeks investment in new plant/ the combination by standing in the way will only encourage invest- ment in excess. If a member of the combination, or a new competitor, is able through the adoption of new machinery or better methods, or by any other advantage that he enjoys, to make his goods at a lower cost than has been possible before^ and therefore to put them on the market at a lower price in the THE PERSISTENCE OF COMPETITION. 33 hope of increasing his sales, the combination must let him make the price and leave other members to conform to it by adopting his methods. Failing to do this, it will but intensify the inevi- table struggle for survival when it comes. It does not invalidate all this that pools sometimes pay would-be competitors for ceas- ing production, and that members of combinations can some- times afford to pay forfeits for price-cutting. These are but means of testing the probable permanence of the existing rela- tions of demand and supply. If the undersupply of the market that tempts new capital is but temporary, the price paid to pre- vent it from entering the field is trre cost of warding off a loss otherwise certain. If the^jandersupply^Qnt'""^ the atteippt uy off competition will only stimulate -it. \i forfeits were graduated according to the degree of price-cutting and the volume of sales, and were made recoverable by the party paying them if he demonstrated his ability to maintain his terms per- manently, they might afford a nearly perfect test of the price the combination must prepare to accept, and a nearly perfect check against underselling for predatory purposes. Expendi- tures in these ways, within the limits dictated by prudence and the lessons of experience, are elements in the cost of produc- tion under modern conditions as legitimate as insurance pre- miums, and it is not impossible that combination actuaries will ice the principles governing combination forfeits to something like scientific form. "If our conclusions so far are sound, can the affirmation be maintained that market competition has illy suppressed^ or that the essential principles of 1 n economics have been overthrown uMn never contemplated com} tion in the production of additional ^oods for a market alre"acly overstocked, or chronic competition in selling goods below the cost of pr(yllirfinn It assumed that when competition had rice of any commodity down to the sum that barely recompensed labor and risk, production and underbidding would cease and labor and capital would find other employment. \\i irdo wrote, this a> ted by commcrc facts. It is only when production is carried on by processes 34 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. involving heavy fixed charges that producers are impelled to continue operations without regard to the state of the market. It is only when large reserves of capital can be drawn on that it is possible to sell below cost, on a great scale, for the sake of winning a strategic advantage. In Ricardo's time these condi- tions did not exist in any trade or manufacture. If, then, com- binations deal effectively only with competition below the sol- vency line, are not the essential Ricardian principles as true to-day as they ever were, and are not Mr. Bagehot's predictions verified P^The competition that wastes resources and ruins com- petitors is an abnormal process that in a sound industrial system will necessarily create reactions against itself. Such competition will probably encounter an increasingly perfect resistance. The competition that forces production to supply fully the social demand, and forces prices down to an equivalence with the cost of production, is normal. Limitation of the range through which the series of competitive acts may extend but increases the amount of normal competition, since by preventing the wasting of capital it increases one of the chief competitive forces. FRANKLIN H. GIDDINGS. PROFITS UNDER MODERN CONDITIONS. WE are drifting toward industrial war for lack of mental analysis. Classes in society are at variance over a ratio of division, and have no clear conception of the thing to be divided. If the profits of business constitute a limitless fund, they furnish a corresponding incentive to strife ; and if this sum is virtual plunder, if it consists of wealth wrested by a social arrangement from the men whose labor creates it, the discon- tented class ought to include every member of society, and will include most members. It needs to be definitely known what profits are, and who earns them ; and again how large they arc, and who actually gets them. The nature of the prize of the social contest and the equities of the case need to be made far clearer than they have been. Adam Smith's " profits of stock" included the general re- turns of the capitalist-employer. More recent writers have recognized that this person performs two functions, and recc; a reward in each capacity. That which accrues to him as a capitalist is interest ; and that which comes to him as an em- ployer, or business manager, is known as entrepreneurs profit. This element is computed by deducting from his gross returns the interest on the capital that he uses. What is not recognized in the prevalent theories is that the entrepreneur as such is a composite person. a furnishing some capital he still performs two unlike functions, and rece. two distinct rewards. Of these rewards one is constant and the other intermittent ; and it is this hr .ent that, as vaguely conceived, constitutes the incentive to social strife. It is the fact of confounding the two functions and merging the rewards attaching to them that has placed economic writers whci has been impossible either to make consistent theories or to comprehend the developments of modern business. 36 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. An entrepreneur is, first, an industrial organizer ; he directs the productive energies of other persons. If he be a manu- facturer he divides and subdivides the labor of making a prod- uct, and assigns to each workman the part of the process to which he is adapted. The thing to be accomplished is pre- scribed ; there is a certain article to be produced, and there is an accepted manner of producing it ; and the routine function which first falls to the employer consists in directing the opera- tion in its execution. He guards against wastes, impels workers to effective effort, and co-ordinates their labors. By his direc- tion the work of many individuals is brought into organic unity. He is the brain of a little social organism ; he does its executive planning, and communicates to the muscles the motive impulses that set them at work and control their action. In this capacity the employer is the most important part of the personnel of the shop. He is a directive laborer. The out- come of his effort is a certain mechanical result, a transforma- tion of matter. Directive labor, muscular labor and machines together create "form utilities " ; they transform iron into im- plements, wool into cloth, etc. ; and in these changes of form lies the value that they jointly bring into existence. Employer and workman are thus far laborers together ; what they get for their efforts is, in the broad sense of the term, wages ; and the employer's part is distinctively the wage of directive labor. In addition to this there comes to an employer a return hav- ing a wholly different origin and nature ; it is essentially mer- cantile. An employer buys, sells and gets gain like any dealer on the street. The business operations of a woolen manufac- turer do not begin with wool in the sorting room, and end with goods in the storehouse. He must obtain the wool from dealers, and must hand the goods over to purchasers. The mechanical part of his business is completed at the mill, and by the work- ing organism of which he is the head ; the mercantile part ex- tends into the world, and brings him into connection with other producing organisms. In this particular exchanging function the workmen have no part ; the employer only is recognized in the market as the buyer of materials and the seller of goods. PROFITS UNDER MODERN CONDITIONS. 37 The buying of raw materials, however, does not end the em- ployer's function as a purchaser ; there is something more to be acquired if he is to become the valid owner of the product. Into the finished goods there enter other elements than raw materials, and these must be in part acquired by purchase. Within the mill itself there are titles to be transferred. Day by day, hour by hour, as the manufacturing goes on, new utili- ties come into existence. Every turn of the engine results in more cloth, more yarn, more carded wool, etc. The utilities thus created have definite values ; unfinished goods may not be immediately salable, but the employer would know how to rate them were he to take an account of stock. Every step in the process that brings them nearer to the condition in which they can be placed upon the market adds something to the value of the crude materials with which the process began. These in- crements of utility are, as we have said, jointly created by three agencies : directive labor, muscular labor and machines. This determines their ownership : they belong, in undivided shares, to the director, the workmen and the furnisher of machines, or the capitalist. Now the essential fact is that the employer buys out his partners in tbe productive operation. He pays for the share of the workmen in wages and for that of the capitalist in int< and acquires thereby a title to the utilities created in the mill. As the raw material is his from the outset, he ends by becoming the owner of every element of the product. In his own name he may place the goods on the market and get what he ca them. The function of the entrepreneur as such consists therefore in two operations, the one mechanical and the other mercan- tile : he directs a productive process, and he buys the elements r into the product and sells them collectively in the product itsdl In the one capacity he is a laborer and ret bet variety of wages; in the <>tl icity he is a chant, and receives a margin of difference Ixtucin what he pays and what he gets. The finished goods are supposed to 38 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. bring in the market more than the cost of all the elements that compose them.1 In a complete study of profits it needs to be noticed that the mercantile part of the employer's function requires both labor and capital. He must spend time in obtaining materials, in making contracts with workmen and capitalists, and in disposing of goods. Here there is a need of labor ; and there is a neces- sity for capital of the circulating kind in the holding of goods until they can be sold and paid for. Mercantile labor as well as mechanical is entitled to wages, and circulating capital as well as fixed is entitled to interest. A mercantile wage constitutes the second part of the general wage of business management ; and an item of interest on circulating capital constitutes a part of the general claim of capital. The labor involved in buying and selling is only incidental to the mercantile function. It is not the essence of it ; that lies in the mere acquiring and surrendering of ownership. It is because the elements that enter into a product come succes- sively into an employer's possession, and then pass collectively out of it, that he can look for a return over and above the wages of every kind of labor and the interest of every kind of capital involved in the business operation. We must group in one item all that comes to an employer in compensation for effort of any kind, and in another all that goes to compensate the capitalist. The general wage of business management constitutes one of the preferred claims on the returns of business ; it must be deducted from them before final profits can be computed. Ordi- nary wages constitute another preferred claim, interest a third and the cost of materials a fourth. If, to avoid intricacy, we group taxes, all forms of insurance and incidental expenses as a fifth claim the sum of these five amounts will represent the total cost of acquiring the title to a product. In selling the product for more than this sum total lies the employer's chance of ultimate gain. Pure profit is the return of simple ownership. It is free from all admixture of wages and of interest. It accrues 1 This analysis of gross profits was published in Work and Wages for March, 1887, in an article by the writer of the present paper. PROFITS UNDER MODERN CONDITIONS. 39 to him who simply extends the aegis of his civil rights over the elements of a product, and then withdraws it in order that the product may pass into other hands. The entrepreneur or assnmcr is he who takes upon himself the responsibility of ownership. That the capitalist, the manager, and the owner of the prod- uct may at times be one and the same person does not affect the analysis ; the three functions are distinct, and the rewards attaching to them are equally so. The growth of corporations tends in a practical way to separate these functions. Capitalists are here a body of stockholders, bondholders and business cred- itors ; managers are a body of salaried officials ; while entre- preneurs, in the limited sense of the term, are the stockholders. Pure profit resides in the portion of the dividends that is in excess of current interest on the paid-up capital. Pure profit is the prize that lures men into business ventures. On this element in the returns of industry are centered the larger expectations of working men. There is no other element from which they can draw a considerable dividend by a change in distribution. Though interest were reduced by a half, and managers' salaries curtailed in the same proportion, the sum thus saved would, as divided among workmen, raise wages only by a small fraction. The elastic margin of pure mercantile profit appears to the undiscerning to be a more promising source of gain. It is important to know how large, under modern con- ditions, this sum is becoming. The elements in the cost of a product are primarily deter- mined by conditions over which the employer has no control. Wages are fixed in the general market for labor ; there is not one rate for a particular manufacturer and another for his rival in the trade, nor are there considerable differences between the rates prevailing in most of the different trades. Labor passes ly from one establishment to another, and even from one industrial group to another, and the permanent tendency of wages is toward uniformity. This large element in the cost of products is fixed by uncontrollable movements in a universal mar Interest is determined by equally general conditions, and is 40 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. uniform to all borrowers who furnish equal guaranties for the certainty and promptness of their payments. The cost of raw materials is determined in a market that is somewhat more limited ; it is gauged by the transactions that take place be- tween the industrial group that produces it and the several groups that use it. This market is broad enough to be beyond individual control. The cost of the labor of management is subject to more dis- turbing influences than almost any other economic element ; and general statements concerning this item of outlay need to be made with adequate reservations. Personal relations may make a particular salary abnormal. The principle that tends to determine the wage of business management may be formu- lated and, with due caution, applied ; it is fixed in a general market for labor of a given intellectual and moral quality. Tried ability and integrity demand high rates of pay, but gravi- tate toward any honorable occupation that offers them ; and the general tendency here as elsewhere is toward a certain uniformity. Rates of insurance and taxation are governed by impartial rules. The elements that constitute the cost of a product to the man who is to own and sell it are fixed by conditions which he cannot change. His returns are equally beyond his control. The price of his product is adjusted in the open market by transactions between the group to which he belongs and the various groups that con- tain his customers. The adjustment is similar to that which governs the price of raw materials. Pure profit is the differ- ence between this uncontrollable amount and the sum of the equally uncontrollable amounts disbursed. The reward of the entrepreneur in his capacity as owner of a product comes to him, as rain from the clouds, through the action of forces lying be- yond the range of his dominant influence. He has nothing to do but to receive it. He must accept what comes into his treasury, and submit to what goes out of it ; the difference, which is pure profit or loss, is fixed without appeal.1 1 Gains effected by the illegitimate manipulation of values, such as is sometimes practiced in Wall Street and elsewhere, do not fall within the scope of this discussion. PROFITS UNDER MODERN CONDITIONS. 41 In his other capacity, that of manager, the entrepreneur is not the helpless creature of fate. His fortune is largely in his own hands. Moreover the fortune of the owner is, in a negative \v:iy, entrusted to the manager, who can always mar it, though he cannot always make it. In a study of profits it needs to be assumed that the shop is running under competent direction ; otherwise, under modern conditions, it will quickly pass from the industrial field. Materials must be well selected, the work- ing force well handled, and the goods rapidly and safely mar- keted, or the pure profit will become a negative quantity, and the business will be terminated. There are transient condi- tions in which mediocrity may for some time hold its place ; but the sword is over its head from the outset, and will fall in due time. The modern struggle for existence means the survival of the fittest type of industrial establishment. Elements that deter- mine the question of fitness are location, working method and managing efficiency. The shop that is unfavorably located yields its business to others; and industries tend automatically to concentrate in places where they can thrive. The mill that uses an antiquated process must change it or stop working ; and industries tend towards uniform mechanical excellence. The establishment that is badly conducted must change its manage- ment or fail ; and business tends to concentrate in the hands of those who conduct it with the greatest energy and wisdom. The centralization of industry gives a special impulse to the tendency to eliminate mediocre management ; it permits a divis- ion of the directive function. There are diversities of gifts in the business world ; the good mechanic may be a bad financier, salesman, etc. The great establishment places in every respon- sible position a man specially adapted to it. The entrepreneur of a highly developed establishment is a collective personality. • p that is under individual direction is no longer typical ; if we continue to speak in the singular number of the man- ager, the owner, and the capitalist, it is to keep in mind the essential unity of the several groups that the terms must really innate. In clear cut distinctness of function, it is as thou-h 42 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. they were individuals ; in efficiency, they greatly surpass them, and tend to supplant them in the industrial field. Modern business demands and secures an aggregation of forces in every department. Groups that have supplanted individual managers continue the competition among themselves, and the entrepre- neur that tends to ultimately survive is a body of men, each one of whom has shown special capacity in his department. The typical modern manager is an organization that is perfect in each separate part. In formulating the principle that gauges the returns of a particular manager at a given time, the analogies between rent and profit are instructive. They have been well utilized by one of the most eminent of living economists, General Francis A. Walker. Having now in view a different end, that of establish- ing a law of development, and of determining the rate toward which the different elements in general profits are tending, I find it possible to derive complementary lessons from the con- trasts presented by the Ricardian principle of rent and the principle that asserts itself in the management of modern business. The area of cultivation in agriculture is governed by a law of extension ; the range of managing ability is subject to a prin- ciple of elimination and contraction. According to accepted formulas the best land is first used, and cultivation then extends to poorer and poorer qualities. The process begins with one grade and ends with many. In general business, various degrees of managing ability come early into the field ; compe- tition eliminates one after another, till the best only is sure of permanent survival. With one qualification, hereafter to be stated, the process begins with many grades and ends, if it is ever completed, with one. The difference in productiveness between the best land and the worst is increasing ; that between the best management and the worst that we need to take account of is diminishing. The rent of lands varies as their qualities, from nothing to an increasingly large sum ; the wages of managers tend, like their business qualities, in the direction of uniformity. PROFITS UNDER MODERN CONDITIONS. 43 Agriculture is dominated by a law of diminishing returns ; and general business by a law of increasing returns. Double the labor and capital expended on an acre of ground and you do not double the crop ; double the labor and capital entrusted to an efficient manager and you more than double the product. The concentration of labor and capital renders more costly the products of agriculture ; and the same influence cheapens those of general business. It follows that the demand for agricultural products tends to outrun the supply ; while the supply of manufactured commod- ities tends to outrun the demand. In the one case increasing population is the primary fact ; and this calls for more food, etc., in spite of the greater cost at which it is obtained. In the other case cheapened production is the primary fact ; and this influence thrusts an increasing product upon the market, notwithstanding the diminished price at which it must be sold. The output of great manufacturing industries is disposed of by a process that tends continually to take on somewhat of the character of a forced sale. The normal condition of many industries is one that, from a business man's point of view, must be termed over- production ; it is the condition in which more is produced at each particular interval than can be sold at prices that through the preceding interval prevailed. It is this final test of over- supply that weak producers cannot endure. The struggle for existence is pending, and industrial groups show various degrees of approach to the consummation to which it leads. In some groups the surviving establishments already in a state of high and nearly uniform efficiency ; while in others they still differ considerably in this respect. There moreover, scattered over the industrial tieKl, an experiment- ing class, whosr * e renders necessary the qualification in the statement of general laws to which reference ady been made. These men are testing their capacity to survh the contest with men « ability. A few win permanent places; the remainder pass from the field; but their ti prc sguises the operation of the la\v of survival. They must be left out of account e to know how far the dcvcl- 44 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. opment has proceeded, and what grade of managing efficiency has a chance of permanent continuance. Any group may have its experimenters who are of greatly inferior quality. The old employer who is about to be crowded from the field marks the margin of survival ; better managers may remain in the field, while worse ones will be cast out. The merging of the functions of owner and manager intro- duces another element of variation, and makes farther care necessary in practically testing the theoretical rule. A man who, besides pure profit, receives a salary and perhaps an ele- ment of interest may not take leave of the competitive field when, according to simple theory, he ought to do so. After profits and interest have vanished he may live on a salary, and may struggle against fate till his capital is curtailed. Through all variations in its application, the law of survival holds true, and places in control of the material fortunes of humanity a class of managing agents who are diminishing in number and improving in quality. They are in fact agents and not princi- pals ; it is the interests of others that are primarily entrusted to their keeping ; for though their wages become relatively high, they are kept within sharp limitations, while the largest fruit of their invaluable labor passes by an irresistible law to society. Wages of management are radically affected by the division of directive labor. The typical modern manager, as already noticed, is a collective personality. Were the rare qualities that are needed for conducting a great enterprise combined in one man he could command a monopoly wage. It would be impossible to replace him, in case he were to leave his employ- ment ; and the limit of his salary would be set only by the paying ability of the capitalist-owner. It is possible to replace any member of a managing organization, and the salaries of the members cannot well be excessive. There is a graded list of candidates for the different positions. Counting rooms are full of potential presidents, secretaries and treasurers ; shops are full of potential superintendents ; and though some of the can- didates may be, by a certain margin of difference, inferior to PROFITS UNDER MODERN CONDITIONS. 45 the men now occupying the higher places, the fact of their presence places a definite check on the salaries that are paid. Experience in work of the higher sort would reduce the differ- ence in quality between the men in the better positions and the candidates for them. The tried man has the preference ; but his tenure of office depends in a measure on his success in what may be termed a continuous competitive examination. There are complications arising from the fact that personal relations to capitalists are not without a large influence on the awarding of the prizes in this contest ; but available candidates are al\\ numerous enough to place a definite limit beyond which the ;es of directive labor may not rise. This element of an employer's returns is determined by active competition in a general market for labor of a certain intrinsic quality. There remains to be determined the amount of pure mercan- tile profit. This is the final element in the analysis of the gross returns of business, and if there are principles governing it, then the division of social wealth is at least a scientific process. Pure profit is the seemingly uncertain quantity which lures men into business, and which figures in the minds of the discon- tented as the prize of agitation. Here, if anywhere, lies the spring that fills the pools of unearned wealth. Pure profit is a vanishing sum. The a priori laws of political economy demand the annihilation of it, and it submits to the decree. In the Ricardian sense of the term the natural amount of this ultimate profit is ;///. It is a positive quantity where the competitive law has not fully asserted itself, and where, within the sphere of its control, it is checked by temporary in- fluence^ nomic orthodoxy concedes to this element no -retical existence ; and where the assumptions of this sys- i concerning competition are reali/cd, the practice of the world becomes orthodox ; pure profit actually disappears. This is an unanticipated vindication of logic. Ricardo did not pre- dict such an outcome, nor did he so far analyze the returns of industry as to distinguish the element that is subject to the law of annihilation. Yet his system involved the principle, and the conformity to it of actual practice is the latter-day triumph of . 46 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. With capital seeking investment at the prevalent rate of in- terest, with directive labor seeking employment at the high rate of wages that its quality demands, can they fail to find each other out, if by union they can each secure a premium ? Can anything prevent them from simultaneously migrating to the point where, besides their wages and interest, they can com- mand an ulterior gain ? Nothing can do so in theory. Ordinary risk is not a barrier, since that is counterbalanced by the item of insurance which in our analysis we have recognized. Eco- nomic formulas call for a prompt migration of labor and capital to the point of special inducement ; and the formulas are justi- fied. A subject of common remark is the reckless promptness with which the movement actually takes place. An employer who is getting more than interest and wages of direction is in- terested to enlarge his product by drawing on the loan fund of the market ; and a capitalist who by engaging in industry can secure more than interest and wages of direction, is interested to create a new establishment by drawing on the market for directive labor. By enlargements from within and accessions from without the productive plant is enlarged, the product in- creased and the price of it reduced to the point at which capital and labor of every kind receive only their normal reward. The point of stable equilibrium is that at which a capitalist- employer realizes neither more nor less than interest on his capital and a salary for his time. Stable equilibrium is not usually rest. Influences may dis- turb the adjustment, and in this instance they do so as regu- larly as it is effected. It is not to be anticipated that the myriad of different industries that occupy the economic field will ever simultaneously reach their natural level of productive- ness. Pure profits will always be found at numerous points, though at no one of them will they prove permanent. If we continue to watch a particular industry we shall see pure profit appearing, as the result of a disturbing influence, and then slowly vanishing, as competition reasserts its control. If we watch the entire industrial field we shall see pure profit appear- ing, now here and now there, shifting forever its place in the field, but never absent from it. PROFITS UNDER MODERN CONDITIONS. 47 One influence which periodically raises the returns of busi- ness above their natural limit is the rhythmical movement of trade, or the fluctuation from underconsumption to over-con- sumption that results from internal changes in the economic system. The period of active demand yields profits where, other conditions remaining the same, that of slackened demand entails losses. The two results should be made to offset each other by averaging the returns of a considerable number of years, if the true status of an industry is to be ascertained. When, in a long interval, the pure profits just balance the losses the natural rate of returns may be considered as maintained. The settlement of a fertile continent is a disturbing influence that may extend through a hundred years, and this period must then be regarded as a prolonged interval of adjustment. Com- petitive law cannot fully vindicate itself while soil exploitation — not agriculture — is pouring treasures into every one's lap. Yet in the end the slow moving law will assert its power. The opening of America to settlement created an originally high level of general profits, from which level competition has re- duced them with varying rates of rapidity. Some localities and some industries still realize abnormal gains from this source. There is another disturbing influence which gives a promise of constantly recurring as long as the economic system con- tinues. It acts intermittently, and on particular industries, but is always present at a thousand different points in the gen- eral field. It is the legitimate creator of pure mercantile profit ; and though we call its action a disturbance, since it counteracts the action of competitive law, yet this influence is as natural as the force that it abrogates. It affords a guaranty for continued civilization. It is the result of a unique human service, that is the most hing in its effects of any that an industrial worker can render. This is the making and applying of inven- tions. While the rest of humanity are working, an elect few are searching. The results of their search come partially and temporarily to themselves ; the major rewards diffuse them- s among the members of society as a whole, who in the end absorb the total gain. The natural rewards of invention 48 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. are the most economical and effective of all possible modes of ensuring the advance of material civilization. They come in a form adapted to secure a maximum result with a minimum of expense to the beneficiaries. They are not stipends, but prizes ; and their effect is to enlist the services of scores of men where only one can receive a personal return. Invention may give to an establishment a temporary monop- oly of a new process or a new product, and raise profit for the time being above the natural level. The making of such dis- coveries is not a part of the routine work of a manager. It does not fall within the scope of any function for which a salary is paid. Some Yankee ingenuity, some power of adapting me- chanical means to ends is indeed required in a successful super- intendent. The exercise of it in minor ways lies within the routine of his business. But the inventions that we are now considering are those that materially change that routine. If a salaried manager makes such an invention, it is extra-official work, and entitles him to the same reward that would accrue to any other inventor. The relations between the makers of inventions and those who introduce them are an interesting subject of study; and so are the effects which the introduction of them has on establish- ments that continue to use the older methods. It is not, how- ever, desirable to obscure our main propositions by too many corollaries. The device that effects an important economy must, in the end, force itself into general use, and thus end the advantage which prior possession gives to its originators. Patents expire, and secrets become known. The public gets a part of the benefit from the first introduction of an economical process, and gets the whole benefit in the end. Competition restores the natural rate of profit, and leaves, as a permanent result, an increase of productive power, an elevation of the level of human life. Patent laws are an evidence that the personal rewards to be gained by this service are too small, rather than too large, and that it is the aim of the state to prolong the fruits of invention beyond the limit of time during which, by natural law, the inventor could enjoy them. PROFITS UXDER MODERN CONDITIONS. 49 If the theory here advanced is true, an inquiry into the busi- ness profits realized in this country during the past few years should show that some industries are, and others are not, ap- proaching the condition in which only natural profits are afforded. Statistics that group several branches of manufac- turing and state returns in the aggregate may be expected to show a profit somewhat above the natural rate ; and figures for the country at large must certainly do so. The general rate of profit in the United States is high, not only because of gains realized by many inventions, but because of returns still realized by the quick exploitation of natural resources. Statistics taken a few years hence would probably eliminate much of this latter variation. The profits from invention would remain, and the returns of any considerable group of industries must be expected to show a permanent average profit somewhat above the natural limit. On the other hand, the returns of particular branches of industry would show, in many cases, a close approximation to the limit. Figures taken in a single case would show the stage of development that one industry has reached ; they would show whether it is still enjoying a residuum of originally high profit, or whether the competitive pressure has reduced its gains to the rate that can be permanently maintained. It will be seen that the facts that we need in order to fully verify our theory are not at present to be had. Fortunately, however, the facts that are most useful are those that relate, in each case, to one specific department of business ; and here the knowledge which each employer in that department pos- sesses is of more than ordinary scientific value. For many purposes aggregates and averages taken from many branches of production are necessary ; and these the business man can- not furnish. For our present purpose averages are misleading, aivl the returns of different departments taken each by it^ give the testimony that we desire. It is not difficult to obtain facts of this kind which strikingly illustrate the tendency of recent influences to crowd profits to a point that affords noth- ing beyond interest and the wages of management. 50 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. The returns of the textile industries of New England, as shown in the report of the Boston stock market, reveal the fact that a few members of this extensive group have, during the fifteen years preceding 1886, enjoyed a certain immunity from the full effects of competitive law. The returns of the group as a whole have, during that interval, been strikingly near to the point of natural profit. The same appears to be true of the shoe and leather industries. The iron and steel manufactures and the numerous branches affiliated with them compose a group so extensive that its average profits would be unavailable for our purpose. Though such gains as those which patents secured to the screw-making industry may now be rare, there are de- partments enough in which competition is held in temporary abeyance to cause considerable deviation from the theoretical standard. Yet within this general group may be found numer- ous cases in which the law is verified ; and the same is true in other parts of the manufacturing field. Public transportation is a department of production essentially peculiar. The local traffic of railroads enjoys a certain im- munity from the full effects of competition. This source of variation from theoretical standards is apparently counter- balanced by influences of an opposite character, and the rail- roads of the United States show an approximation to the normal rate of profits that is even closer than that of the textile industries. More and better statistics than are now available are certain soon to be collected ; and there is no risk in affirm- ing that where the prescribed conditions exist, the normal rate of profits will be realized. Labor of every sort will be paid for ; capital will be rewarded ; but there will be no bonus for any one.1 We are living in a half-developed system, and in the law of its growth may discern more clearly than was formerly possible an outline of the form that it will ultimately take. That law connects the rewards of business life with services, and gauges them in amount by the value of those services. It gives more 1 I am indebted to the Hon. Joseph H. Walker, of Worcester, Mass., for statistics tending to show that, in manufacturing industries, profits in excess of the natural rate, when they are not secured by inventions, have of late been rapidly disap- pearing. PROFITS UNDER MODERN CONDITIONS. 5 I to intellect than to muscle, and more to character than to either ; the largest stipends that it offers are for fidelity to trusts. It checks undue discrimination in favor of mere position, and ensures to the men in the industrial ranks rates of pay not too far below those enjoyed by their leaders. It offers special prizes for the discovery of secrets of effective work. It limits more closely than statute law could do the personal benefits that accrue to the men who render this service, so that when the law is invoked it is for the purpose of increasing them. By organization and discovery it constantly places humanity upon new vantage ground in the struggle for well-being. Less and less, measured in effort, is becoming the cost of a day's enjoy- ments ; greater and greater, measured in enjoyments, are the returns of a day's labor. In cheapened production, which is never appreciated, and is often blindly resisted, lies, according to this social law, the chief hope for modern workers. The leaders and discoverers whose labor ensures this constant gain find their rewards limited in amount and in time, while the wealth that they diffuse throughout society is, in both direc- tions, limitless. The outline of the coming industrial state has the shape neither of despotism nor of democracy ; it is the outline of a true republic. JOHN B. CLARK. THE NATURAL RATE OF WAGES. IN his chapter on " Popular Remedies for Low Wages " John Stuart Mill described a certain " considerable body of existing opinion on the subject." The opinion here referred to was not critical opinion merely, it was also opinion as an active force. Taking form in legislation, or, less coercivcly, in moral influence, it undertook to provide that the workman should have "reasonable" or "sufficient" wages. That is, it was exerted to maintain wages " above the point to which they would be brought by competition." As in Mr. Mill's time, so now, there are two sets of forces operating with reference to the rate of wa^es. One set is com- posed of the forces of competition. Their action is automatic. Their resultant is a mechanical equilibrium. The other forces are self-conscious forms of human feeling: and opinion. They set up a standard of justice, and take form in moral judgments, appeals to reason, the policy of labor organizations, legislation, and administration. Whatever their efficacy for good or ill, the self-conscious forces are acquiring an increasing prominence. In regard to these two kinds of forces that make, or are supposed to make, the rate of wages, we may discover three different views among economic thinkers. By economists of severely deductive habits and somewhat reactionary tendencies, the self-conscious forces are dismissed as of no importance except as a disturbing element. They are regarded as impotent to affect the rate of wages in the long run. Competition is held to be the only agency that needs to be con- sidered, because, sooner or later, the rate of wages will be made inexorably, in the outworking of an automatic natural process. Another class of thinkers, if we may call them such, deniers of natural law in the social world, reach the opposite conclusion. Competition they regard as a kind of human conduct that can be checked and presently made end of, like crime or intemper- THE NATURAL RATE OF WAGES. 53 ance. The self-conscious social efforts are believed to be quite sufficient, if fully put forth, to make the rate of wages, so far as the making is an affair of distributing a certain total product among the parties engaged in its production. According to a third and middle view, the self-conscious forces sustain some relation to the physical and automatic forces iy of limitation and supplement. Just what this relation is, is a fact for scientific investigation to determine. In science, as in practical affairs, the mean hypothesis is often more promising than either extreme, and it certainly is so in the highly complex sciences of social phenomena. Assuming then, provisionally, that the rate of wages is the resultant of competitive and moral forces acting simultaneously, the true wages problem, as it presents itself to the economist to-day, is to resolve this resultant, and ascertain whether it lies mainly within the projection of the competitive, or mainly within the projection of the moral forces. I. \Ve may conveniently begin the study of this problem by examining the standards of ideal, or just, wages, that are set up, and attempting to decide what, if any, is their common and valid content. We may then study the competitive process as it goes on in the absence of consciously imposed restrictions and ascertain how nearly the results approximate to the ideal. v, we may inquire whether the application of the self- conscious forces serves, or can serve, to make the approximation more complete. \Ve are so accustomed to make a sharp distinction between the communistic and the individualistic ideals of society that it i absurd to affirm that, within rather broad limits, there is no absolute contradiction between the communistic rule : "From each according to his abilities, to each MIL; to his ," and the individualistic rule : "To each according to the value of his work." But if we go back to organic princip! shall soon discover that, as a general and average fact; the one 54 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. rule cannot mean anything else than the other, and that, so far as the two do not coincide they correct each other. Taking the phenomena of life as a whole, there is, and must be, an equivalence between needs and work, and an equivalence between the satisfaction of needs and the existence of abilities to work. Needs are, in general, but the requirements of certain things to replace the tissue consumed in physical and mental efforts, or to build up and develop tissue for greater future efforts. These efforts, adjusted to useful ends, are work, and apart from work, therefore, there are no genuine needs. Ex- cepting the needs of childhood, old age and misfortune — excep- tions more nominal than real — desires or requirements for other ends than those of useful service for self or others are pseudo- needs, illegitimate in economy as in ethics. The satisfaction of needs is not limited, however, to the mere restitution of an exact equivalent of human energy already expended. To some extent it anticipates work to be done. Nature makes generous advances to her children, but inexorably enforces payment.1 A given amount of food contains more energy, usually, to be set free through its consumption, than was expended in obtain- ing it. Consequently, the value of work is usually a little more than the value of the antecedent work from which it was evolved. To these advances persistently utilized — advances converted into abilities, abilities in turn put forth in work — the progress of mankind from savagery to civilization has been due. Occasional and individual misadjustments between needs and work are sure to occur, because social changes make misadjust- ments of every possible kind. It is in order then to inquire how the misadjustment comes about, and what is its true cor- rection. It may be that men whose needs have been and are fully supplied are not converting their supplies into an equiva- lent of useful work, or it may be that men who are willing to work and have the will to develop their abilities beyond present 1 Professor Sumner's assertion : " Whenever nature yields to man an atom which he has not earned, or advances it one second of time before he has earned it, we may all turn socialists and utopists " (Collected Essays in Political and Social Science, p. 50), contradicts the truth of both biology and history. THE NATURAL RATE OF WAGES. 55 limits are inadequately supplied with what they need. Obviously the remedy in the one case is to bring educational disciplines to bear ; in the other to correct, as far as possible, errors in distribution. The correction belongs for the most part within the sphere of moral effort, education, and philanthropy. It belongs to economic effort so far as the value of the laborer's work falls below the amount that will both recompense him for energy expended, and afford him something for the development of his potential abilities ; for this is its natural value, the value nature commonly gives it. The rule of ideal distribution is, to each according to the full natural value of his work. II. Such being the ideal, how far does the competitive process tend to make it actual ? What is the rate of wages in the absence of self-conscious agencies acting in other than com- petitive ways ? English political economy has always more or less distinctly affirmed that in any society there is a certain natural rate of wages. The first description of natural wages was strikingly different from the definition that soon after gained acceptance. It was Adam Smith's saying, — the first sentence in his discus- sion of wages, — that " the produce of labor constitutes the natural recompense or wages of labor," and was made in view of "that original state of things" when there was neither land- lord nor master, and the whole produce of industry belonged to the laborer. The truth, so fundamental in our modern philosophy of wages, that in a later industrial state also- whcn the active population has been differentiated into vari- ous classes of employers and employed — the wages of the laborer are still approximately equivalent to what he produces, ked out in 77 ':/i of Nations. If Adam Smith ever distinctly perceived that the employer's profit is value created by his own services, not by the laborer's exer- tions, the idea was no link in the chain of thought that took shape in the chapter on wages. Consequently, in treating of 56 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. labor as conditioned by landlord and master, his thought gravi- tates to the minimum limit to which wages can be forced by competition. "There is, however," he says, "a certain rate below which it seems impossible to reduce, for any considera- ble time, the ordinary wages even of the lowest species of labor." This rate is the wage that will maintain the laborer, and enable him to rear another laborer to take his place in the next generation. If the wealth of a country were stationary, the competition of the laborers and the interest of the masters would soon reduce wages to this lowest rate which is consistent with common humanity. If wealth is increasing, and so long as it continues to increase, wages will be above the minimum. If wealth were decreasing, wages would fall below the lowest humane rate until, by famine, " the number of inhabitants in the country was reduced to what could easily be maintained by the revenue and stock which remained in it." 1 This analysis was seized upon by Ricardo, who condensed it into a definition. Giving a new, and, as it proved, permanent meaning to the term "natural" which Adam Smith had used in a sense so different, Ricardo defined natural wages as "that price which is necessary to enable the laborers, one with another, to subsist and to perpetuate their race without either increase or diminution."2 To its author this definition meant a great deal more than the words explicitly affirm. Saying nothing of Ricardo's analysis of minimum wages in terms of food, which we need not follow, it is plain that the limit below which he supposed wages could not permanently fall is considerably above the minimum described by Adam Smith. He assumed that the laborer was master of the minimum rate below which wages could not be permanently lowered. "It is not to be under- stood," he said, "that the natural price of labor, estimated even in food and necessaries, is absolutely fixed and constant. It varies at different times in the same country, and very mate- rially differs in different countries. It essentially depends on the habits and customs of the people." It is safe to say that 1 The Wealth of Nations, chapter viii. 2 Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, chapter v. THE NATURAL RATE OF WAGES. 57 if this last assumption of Ricardo's had been warranted by the facts of the actual industrial world, English political economy would have escaped the wrath of humanitarians and the name of a dismal science. But when John Stuart Mill restated and elaborated the body of doctrine evolved by his predecessors, he was not long in proving that the moral minimum of wages was a myth. Any disadvantageous change in the circumstances of laborers, — that is, any reduction of actual below natural wages, — he pointed out, "may permanently lower the standard of living of the class in case their previous habits in respect of popula- jtion prove stronger than their previous habits in respect of com- Jqrt. In that case the injury done will be permanent, and their deteriorated condition will become a new minimum tending to perpetuate itself as the more ample minimum did before;"1 and this has happened and does happen so frequently as to render all propositions ascribing a self-repairing quality to the calami- ties which befall the laboring classes, practically of no validity. III. Yet it does not follow that there is not a true natural rate of wages, well above the limit at which a man must starve or beg. There is a soul of truth in Ricardo's idea, and it happens to be the only part of the doctrine that the economist, as such, is really concerned with. Far above the limit of mere subsistence there is a limit below which the permanent reduction of wages is uneconomical. The maximum production of wealth depends on the most complete and perfect division of labor, and the division of labor depends not only on the extent of the market but on the size of the population. The extent of the market i di-pcnds on the size of the producing and consuming popu- lation, and an occupation ran become differentiated from allied occupations and developed into a distinct trade, business, or ion, only when th ruble number of persons to engage in it. There is, therefore, a limit below which the reduction of the laboring population reduces the incomes not 1 Principles of Political Economy, book ii, chapter xi. 58 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. only of laborers themselves but of all classes in the community. The farmer cannot develop the resources of his land, or the manufacturer increase his product. The reward of management is curtailed and interest reduced. Again, there is for each laborer a maximum efficiency in proportion to his consumption. Up to a certain point the more real wages put into him the more useful service can be gotten out of him. To quote once more from Adam Smith, the industrial experience of a century has been but cumulative proof of his saying : " A plentiful sub- sistence increases the bodily strength of the laborer, and the comfortable hope of bettering his condition and of ending his days in ease and plenty animates him to exert that strength to the utmost."1 As statistical science and methods improve, it should be possible to ascertain the economical rate of wages for any given occupation at any given time, and with a fair approximation to accuracy, by means of statistical averages drawn from selected results. These would include statistics of the cost of labor of the same nationality, employed under sub- stantially similar conditions except differences of real wages. Now this economical rate is none other than the ethical rate. To give the laborer the wage that calls out his full efficiency and affords him a comfortable hope for old age, is to give him no less than that sum which is sufficient to develop his potential abilities. In communities accustomed to change and progress, the actual rate of wages must equal this ethical and economical rate, or fall very much below it. Where the ideas and aspira- tions of the successful are communicated to all classes the laborer can never remain in an equilibrium of contentment. The stimulus and tone of his life is the prospect of doing better. Remove that stimulus and he does not simply remain a station- ary economic quantity, he deteriorates from that moment. His efficiency is impaired, he adds less and less to the world's sum total of wealth. Losing the ambition to do as well as he can, he loses also the ambition to live as well as he can, to make the most of what he has. He falls into unsanitary habits. His vitality and that of his children is impaired, and, while he may 1 The Wealth of Nations, chapter viii. THE NATURAL RATE OF WAGES. 59 have as many children as he would have if living in wholesome prosperity, not as many of them will survive to maturity. Both in efficiency and in numbers the labor force is diminished, and the total production of society is lessened. Consequently, in a community advancing in wealth and refinement, that cannot be an economical rate of wages which is insufficient to enable the workingman to share in the general expansion of life. Giving to the laborer the full natural value of his work, the economical rate of wages is no less than the produce of his labor. The economical rate, moreover, is the rate to which wages actually would conform if competition were governed only by the expectation of gain, and the losses of excessive competition could not be shifted by the competitors upon others. Competition carried to the extent of keeping wages as low as this rate is beneficial to all. It forces men to make the most of their opportunities, it sharpens thought and disciplines char- acter, and calls the creative powers into fullest action. Carried the least degree farther, competition merely deadens and destroys, and the majority of men do not habitually carry competition to destructive lengths when acting freely by the impulse of natural motives. The economic limit of competition is its natural limit — not always its actual limit — and the rate of wages made by competition restricted within this limit is a natural rate. Therefore, in the fullest sense, the economical rate is at once the true natural and the true ethical rate of wages. Stripped of fallacy and rightly developed, the Ricardian doctrine of natural wages is identical with the earlier affirmation of Adam Smith. The natural remuneration of the laborer is the produce of his labor, and in an improving society this produce is not less than the "reasonable" and "sufficient" wages which humani- tarian feeling demands. IV. Let us now inquire to what extent the actual rate of wages, so far as competition determines it, tends to conform to the natural i 60 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. The wages-fund doctrine has been finally overthrown, and it has been abundantly demonstrated that the actual rate of wages is made by the productiveness of industry : but the proposition has not been reduced to perfect definiteness. That is to say, it is no longer disputed that wages are more when product is more and less when product is lees, but there is still dispute whether increasing production tends to benefit chiefly the employer or chiefly the laborer. The decisive answer to this question will be given some day by statistics. Meanwhile we can satisfy ourselves on two important points. The formula of Cobden that wages rise when two bosses are after one man and fall when two men are after one boss, means that every increase in the number of employers who can make a sufficient profit from their business to maintain themselves as employers, acts favorably on the rate of wages. And this is true, notwithstanding the fact that consolidations of productive undertakings, concentrating them in the hands of the most competent men, are attended with economy of production. So long as new employers can find a place in any industry, and profitably maintain themselves in it, the benefits arising from concentration have not yet been distributed in wages and reduced prices of utilities. The profits of the employers hitherto in the field have been abnormally large. It is not the intrusion of poorer employers into the field that increases the profits of abler employers, any more than it is the actual resort to poorer land that increases the rent of better land. It is the increasing value of the produce of the best land, due to its failure to supply an increasing demand upon it, that makes the profitable cultivation of poorer land possible and affords rent to the best. The actual cultivation of the worst land that can be cultivated with profit establishes a limit beyond which the value of the produce of the best land cannot rise. But for the prod- uce of poor land the owners of fertile land could obtain famine prices.1 So of employers. If there is any condition necessi- ' tating a resort to poorer employers it is the failure of the best * 1 Malthus understood, or at least stated, the cause of rent more accurately than Ricardo. Cf. James Bonar, Malthus and his Work. THE NATURAL RATE OF WAGES. 6 1 employers to supply the demand for employer functions. The number of men of superlative business genius is small, and the powers of the ablest men are not unlimited. If there were no resort to a commoner grade of talent the value of the employer function would rise above any assignable price. So far from deducting in any way from the laborer's real wages, the multi- plication of employers who can sustain themselves above bank- ruptcy reduces the prices of goods and increases the wages of labor. Does a condition of improving industry tend to multiply employers ? The true answer to this question is that the num- ber of employers tends to multiply just as far as the more gifted employers, or combinations of gifted employers, fail to discharge the employer function with decreasing cost to the community, thereby leaving for real wages an increasing portion of the total product of industry. This law is absolute. That combinations economize production we know. It is one of the most striking phenomena of modern industrial life. It is as if the owners of superior lands should discover some means by which increasing investments of capital in agriculture should yield increasing, instead of diminishing, returns. They could then drive the cultivators of the poorer lands out of the market if they chose, but only by dividing their increasing gains with consumers. Should they attempt to retain all, the humbler cul- tivators would again meet them in the market. It is the same with employers. Centralization of the employer function and \tinction of the smaller employers is possible only by con- veying to the laborer a larger share of product than he previ- ously enjoyed. There is, indeed, a limit in every industry beyond which the intrusion of new competitors will ensure the bankruptcy of some ; and when that limit is reached the stronger survivors >r, by a judicious policy as to prices, to hold the field. But there remains the limitless domain of itilitics, and the ition of utilities depends not only on that geographical extension of the market which Adam Smith described, but even more, under modern conditions, on the productiveness of industry, the greater or lesser incomes of 62 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. the people. When a man's income is increasing he does not increase all his expenses in proportion ; he adds some new ones outright, purchases some utilities that he did not enjoy before. \Yhen his income is decreasing he lops off some at a stroke. From all this it would appear that in communities enjoying increasing prosperity the actual rate of wages must tend con- stantly to conform to that true natural rate which is at once the economical and the ethical rate. That this is, indeed, the real tendency in the industrial nations at the present time, there is much reason to believe ; but there are, unfortunately, many exceptions extending over large areas of population and through long intervals of time. To conform to the natural rate would be the real tendency everywhere and always, if competi- tion were always uniform and normal. But in the actual indus- trial world competition is never uniform, and because not uniform it is often carried to ruinous excess. V. I have elsewhere shown that the competitive process, judged by economic or ethical standards, is inherently defective,1 and this because, like all natural processes, it assumes a rhythmical form. " Competition begins only after gains in excess of nor- mal profits have accrued to employing producers. As a conse- quence of this fact, when competition does begin it goes to excess." When, passing the normal limit, competition assumes that terrible intensity that presages business ruin, the employer is driven to every expedient to save some part of his narrowing margin of profit. The readiest expedient, the most available for the moment, though costliest in the end, is the exploitation of wages. In a mild way this is done by tacitly or openly restricting competition in the purchase of labor. Whatever brings additional employers into productive enterprise and in- tensifies competition in the sale of products will naturally in- tensify competition in the purchase of labor ; but we must be careful not to confound the two processes. To some extent it 1 The Theory of Profit Sharing, Quarterly Journal of Economics, April, 1887. THE NATURAL RATE OF WAGES. 63 is easily possible for employers to separate them in their indus- trial practice, thereby adding to their profits a sum that would otherwise be added to wages. In its worst and most brutal form the exploitation of wages becomes a positive extortion from working men and women who have been reduced by mis- fortunc to such straits that all power of resistance is gone. It becomes the "sweating" system of the clothing trades, the "plucking" system of the coal districts. Between these ex- tremes are all those gradations that substitute the labor of women for the labor of men, the labor of children for the labor of women, and replace the native laborer with a foreign compet- itor of a lower grade of life. All these exploitations, reducing ;es below the true economical rate, react disastrously on production, in time, and are contrary to the interests of em- ployers as a class ; but they profit for a while, and may continu- ously profit the individual employer who can shift upon society or his competitors the losses that his practice creates. He divides his ill-gotten gains with the consumer, and thereby, commanding the market, compels worthier competitors to adopt his methods. Now to these deplorable results of ill-regulated competition there is no automatic correction, springing from motives of individual self-interest, that meets the case. The wide-spread belief that, if the exploitation of wages is carried so far as actu- ally to enrich the employer, the sum so gained, if converted into capital, will return to labor, is still shared by many respectable economists. It is true to the extent that increasing capital does act favorably on wages. In overthrowing the wages-fund doctrine economists have somewhat lost sight of the real func- tion performed by capital in employing labor. The owners of accumulating capital, casting about for productive investments, ct, according to their best judgment, those that promise to yield the best returns. Labor for such new enterprises must be drawn, by the offer of increased wages, from other employ- ments— to some extent even when there is a large body of unemployed workmen, since the unemployed are always the relatively inefficient. Even the replacement of old capital gives 64 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY. rise to this process of selection among actual and possible enter- prises with reference to their anticipated profitableness, and the consequent drafting of labor from the less profitable to the more profitable employments. The accumulation of new capital amplifies and accelerates it. Hence the ratio of capital to popu- lation, though having in its static aspect no such relation to wages as the old doctrines ascribed to it, has yet a dynamic relation that is definite and important. But when the capital has been wrung from labor, the original wrong is never righted. The capital has become the property of the employer, and has increased his power. The way in which it has been obtained has cultivated the disposition to acquire power in that way by continuing to exploit wages, even when indus- trial conditions no longer afford an excuse. The loss sus- tained by the laborer may never be repaired, for degradations of men and women are converted into organic changes. A lower type of life is the result, and ultimately the reaction is completed in a positive impairment of the productive force of the community. Neither are the evil results of unequal competition corrected by efforts springing from altruistic motives, so long as these are not reinforced by associated action. The ultimate cure for industrial evils is, indeed, in the growth of altruistic feeling. Employers must cease to exploit wages, either to avoid loss or to increase their profit and power. They and others must endeavor, by personal help and encouragement, to counteract the tendency to degradation in the unfortunate and discouraged. But that these efforts on the part of those who have the dispo- sition to make them may avail, a restraint must be put on those who have no such disposition. Unselfish men, acting as indi- viduals, without reference to each other, would be crowded out in the struggle for survival. That ninety-nine fair employers may have a chance, there must be some restraint upon the hun- dredth unfair one ; and that restraint can be effectively organ- ized only by the interests injuriously affected. It must be their united resistance and co-operation. THE NATURAL RATE OF WAGES. 65 VI. So we are brought, at last, to consider the action of those self-conscious forms of feeling and opinion which undertake to govern the competitive process by such means as the policy of labor organizations and legislation. What can they accomplish ? It requires neither argument nor marshalling of facts to prove that by no means whatever can employers be forced to surren- der from their gross profits, for addition to the wages of their employees, any part of the sum that constitutes the normal reward of the employer function. Any attempt, temporarily successful, to secure more, would simply drive employers out of business and throw labor out of employment. But when competition among the undertakers of enterprise is carried to its full normal limits there will be no ulterior profit in excess of such reward of the entrepreneur function as will maintain that function unimpaired. With capital accumulating for in- vestment, the competition of producers as sellers of their pro- ducts is sure to reach its full normal limits. The only sums, then, that can be added to wages by any means whatever are: First, the sum labor is in danger of losing, either (i) through the failure of employers to compete as freely as purchasers of labor as they compete as sellers of products, or (2) by that merciless competition which takes advantage of the laborer's ignorance or weakness to rob him and divides the plunder between the employing producer and the buyer of goods. Secondly, the sum that might be produced by calling into action any potential manhood and ability. of the laborer that actual competition fails to develop. Can as much as this be accomplished? I ^ power of the labor organization is the strike^ actual or in . e, and back of the strike the ability of the organization to hold together. Unless there is some ulterior motive for permit- ting the strike, the employer can better afford to yield to the demand of labor any sum less than the amount the strike will cost him and not exceeding the aggregate of the sums above de- scribed as possible additions towages. Lit us designate this aggregate by